CHAP. VIII. | |||
OF THE WAGES OF LABOUR. | |||
The produce of labour constitutes the natural | |||
recompence or wages of labour. | |||
In that original state of things which precedes | |||
both the appropriation of land and the | |||
accumulation of stock, the whole produce of | |||
labour belongs to the labourer. He has neither | |||
landlord nor master to share with him. | |||
Had this state continued, the wages of labour | |||
would have augmented with all those | |||
improvements in its productive powers, to | |||
which the division of labour gives occasion. | |||
All things would gradually have become | |||
cheaper. They would have been produced by | |||
a smaller quantity of labour; and as the commodities | |||
produced by equal quantities of labour | |||
would naturally in this state of things be | |||
exchanged for one another, they would have | |||
been purchased likewise with the produce of | |||
a smaller quantity. | |||
But though all things would have become | |||
cheaper in reality, in appearance many things | |||
might have become dearer, than before, or | |||
have been exchanged for a greater quantity of | |||
other goods. Let us suppose, for example, | |||
that in the greater part of employments the | |||
productive powers of labour had been improved | |||
to tenfold, or that a day's labour could | |||
produce ten times the quantity of work which | |||
it had done originally; but that in a particular | |||
employment they had been improved only | |||
to double, or that a day's labour could produce | |||
only twice the quantity of work which | |||
it had done before. In exchanging the produce | |||
of a day's labour in the greater part of | |||
employments for that of a day's labour in this | |||
particular one, ten times the original quantity | |||
of work in them would purchase only twice | |||
the original quantity of it. Any particular | |||
quantity in it, therefore, a pound weight, for | |||
example, would appear to be five times dearer | |||
than before. In reality, however, it would be | |||
twice as cheap. Though it required five times | |||
the quantity of other goods to purchase it, it | |||
would require only half the quantity of labour | |||
either to purchase or to produce it. The | |||
acquisition, therefore, would be twice as easy | |||
as before. | |||
But this original state of things, in which | |||
the labourer enjoyed the whole produce of his | |||
own labour, could not last beyond the first introduction | |||
of the appropriation of land and | |||
the accumulation of stock. It was at an end, | |||
therefore, long before the most considerable | |||
improvements were made in the productive | |||
powers of labour; and it would be to no purpose | |||
to trace further what might have been | |||
its effects upon the recompence or wages of | |||
labour. | |||
As soon as land becomes private property, | |||
the landlord demands a share of almost all the | |||
produce which the labourer can either raise or | |||
collect from it. His rent makes the first deduction | |||
from the produce of the labour which | |||
is employed upon land. | |||
It seldom happens that the person who tills | |||
the ground has wherewithal to maintain himself | |||
till he reaps the harvest. His maintenance | |||
is generally advanced to him from the | |||
stock of a master, the farmer who employs | |||
him, and who would have no interest to employ | |||
him, unless he was to share in the produce | |||
of his labour, or unless his stock was to | |||
be replaced to him with a profit. This profit | |||
makes a second deduction from the produce | |||
of the labour which is employed upon land. | |||
The produce of almost all other labour is | |||
liable to the like deduction of profit. In all | |||
arts and manufactures, the greater part of the | |||
workmen stand in need of a master, to advance | |||
them the materials of their work, and | |||
their wages and maintenance, till it be completed. | |||
He shares in the produce of their labour, | |||
or in the value which it adds to the materials | |||
upon which it is bestowed; and in this | |||
share consists his profit. | |||
It sometimes happens, indeed, that a single | |||
independent workman has stock sufficient both | |||
to purchase the materials of his work, and to | |||
maintain himself till it be completed. He is | |||
both master and workman, and enjoys the | |||
whole produce of his own labour, or the whole | |||
value which it adds to the materials upon which | |||
it is bestowed. It includes what are usually | |||
two distinct revenues, belonging to two distinct | |||
persons, the profits of stock, and the | |||
wages of labour. | |||
Such cases, however, are not very frequent; | |||
and in every part of Europe twenty workmen | |||
serve under a master for one that is independent, | |||
and the wages of labour are everywhere | |||
understood to be, what they usually are, when | |||
the labourer is one person, and the owner of | |||
the stock which employs him another. | |||
What are the common wages of labour, depends | |||
everywhere upon the contract usually | |||
made between those two parties, whose interests | |||
are by no means the same. The workmen | |||
desire to get as much, the masters to give | |||
as little, as possible. The former are disposed | |||
to combine in order to raise, the latter in order | |||
to lower, the wages of labour. | |||
It is not, however, difficult to foresee which | |||
of the two parties must, upon all ordinary occasions, | |||
have the advantage in the dispute, | |||
and force the other into a compliance with | |||
their terms. The masters, being fewer in number, | |||
can combine much more easily: and the | |||
law, besides, authorises, or at least does not | |||
prohibit, their combinations, while it prohibits | |||
those of the workmen. We have no acts of | |||
parliament against combining to lower the | |||
price of work, but many against combining | |||
to raise it. In all such disputes, the masters | |||
can hold out much longer. A landlord, a | |||